Michael Bluejay's info & resources about

Michael Bluejay's Home Page | Email me

Home Austin Co-ops ICC History Articles & Resources

How to Lower Room Rates in the Summer by $80/mo.
Feb. 2004

This was written for ICC-Austin, but the discussion is applicable to any co-op system where the members don't automatically enjoy lower rates when occupancy improves.

[Note: If the rebate described below kicks in after 69% occupancy instead of 75% occupancy, then room rates can decrease by $90-$96/mo. rather than just $80. I haven't had time yet to rewrite this page to reflect that option, but the concept is still right on, so read this anyway.]

In a related article we saw why room rates are so high, and why there's nearly nothing you can easily cut from the budget. (article) We saw that the only three ways to meaningfully lower rates are:

  • Downsize staff and have the members do the work instead
  • Buy more houses and spread our costs out over a greater number of members
  • Increase occupancy to get more money coming in

In this article we'll explore the last option, increasing occupancy.

 

Higher Occupancy = Lower Rates

Let's say we need to make $6000 to pay for our expenses. We could divide that by ten people, so each would pay $600. That's kind of like what we're doing today, people in singles pay around $600/mo. during the long term.

But what if we had 11 people kicking in money? Then everyone would only have to kick in $545. Ta-da, you saved money.

In fact, that's one of the whole points of co-ops, to pool resources so everyone can save money. The more people kicking in, the less everyone pays. But when fewer people kick in, everyone pays more. That's what's happening in ICC. Those empty rooms are money out of your pocket. If ICC were full your rates could easily be more than $50/mo. lower.

Lower Rates = Higher Occupancy

It cuts both ways. Having higher occupancy allows us to lower rates. But lowering rates itself can give us higher occupancy, because more people want to live here when the rates are cheaper. So it's possible to lower rates and not lose any money. We could make up for the lower rates by having more people live here.

In fact, that's what I've proposed to the board for the last several years in a row now: slash summer rates and try to make up the loss with increased occupancy. But the board has been understandably reluctant to lower rates, because what if the increased occupancy didn't happen? Then if we have the same number of members but at lower rates, we'd be screwed.

Since the board has rejected my idea consistently because they don't want to gamble on having better occupancy I had to put my head towards coming up with a plan that would make lowering rates in the summer less risky....

Lower rates by ~$15/mo. for each extra member in a house

Here's the plan. It's so simple I don't know why I (or anybody else) didn't think of it sooner: Rates start out at the typical level. But for each extra member who moves into the house, each member of the house pays ~$15/mo. less. (More or less, depending on the size of the house in question.) Fill up the typical six vacancies and everybody pays $80/mo. less.

This ties the rate reduction directly to increased occupancy. Rates don't go down until we already have the extra occupancy that allows us to reduce the rates. Problem solved. This is also what many other co-ops do -- refund the profits directly to the members.

Below are the details of how this plan could work.

Details of the plan

Let's see how much money an extra member brings in. Most vacancies in the summer are doubles, so if a vacancy is filled it will probably be a double. Last year's rate for a double (03-04) was $414/mo. A new member is going to eat the $105/mo. in food (current rates) use about $25 in utilities. So we can expect to get $414 - 105 - 25 = $284/mo. from a new member in a double. This is how much we can divvy among all the members in the house to lower rates.

Of course, the amount that rates go down depends on how many members we're dividing among. Members in smaller houses will see a bigger reduction per member than members in bigger houses. Now before people in bigger houses start screaming that this is unfair, look at it a little closer: Bigger houses get to start out with more vacancies than smaller houses. New Guild starts out with more than twice as many vacancies as 1910 for the same room rate. It all evens out.

So now let's figure out how many vacancies each house can start with. We typically budget for 75% occupancy during the summer. So here's how many people we expect to have in each house, and how many vacancies.

Capacity
Expected
(75%, rounded)
Expected
Vacancies

1910

14
10
4

Arrakis

20
15
5

Avalon

23
17
6

French

20
15
5

Helios

17
13
4

HoC

27
20
7

New Guild

32
24
8

Royal

17
13
4

Seneca

19
14
5

Based on that we can figure how much rates can go down per person in each house, for each extra member who moves in:

Rate Reduction Per Member
for each vacancy filled

1910

$20

Arrakis

$16

Avalon

$13

French

$16

Helios

$20

HoC

$11

New Guild

$10

Royal

$20

Seneca

$16

I didn't show my work for how I arrived at this, but here's the gist of it: I divided the $284 in extra revenue from filling a double by the number of members in the house, assuming that the house has filled exactly half its vacancies. Then I rounded all the figures. Then I multiplied the result by the number of vacancies to see the maximum rate reduction per member in a 100% full house. Then I adjusted the amounts so that the maximum rate reduction in each house would be about $80/mo.

Overcoming objections

I've been around ICC long enough that I can already tell what the objections will be. So let's tackle them one at a time.

Members would simply move to whatever house had the best occupancy.

This is easily solved by making members forfeit their rate reduction if they switch houses after the summer has already started.

Members would simply get degenerates to sign for rooms who had no intention of paying, just so the presence of a warm body would lower everyone's rates.

This is easily solved by requiring that houses have to bring the unpaid charges below a certain % before everyone gets their rate reduction.

One house could have 90% occupancy while another could have 50%. Without your plan the extra occupancy from the 90% house would subsidize the 50% house. So with your plan we'll lose money.

Look at this a little closer. First of all, if a house has 90% in the summer, it's probably because of the rate reduction. Without the rate reduction the house probably wouldn't be nearly that full.

Second, it's important to reward houses that kick ass even if other houses lag behind. Nothing saps morale like not recognizing the contributions of the people who are trying hard. If members bust their butts and get their house fuller, then they deserve their rate reduction, plain and simple.

Third, there's already a cushion built in: The rate reduction is based on filling up doubles, but we'll almost certainly fill up some singles too. The extra money we get from a single can make up for houses with poorer occupancy.

Finally, the amount of money we'd "lose" isn't that great. In the example above we're talking $2300 for the whole summer. Out of a $1,000,000 budget, it's a drop in the bucket. And that's ignoring the doubles vs. singles cushion, and the fact that a house with very high occupancy probably wouldn't have that high occupancy in the absence of the rate reduction.

This isn't fair because singles bring in more than doubles so the numbers should be different. And with each new member in the house the rate reduction should drop less and less because there are more members to divide among, so you need to make a whole table to figure out the rate reductions. And some consideration should be made if some houses really poor occupancy while others have really good occupancy.

Let me make my position on this very clear: No, no, no, no, no! It is not necessary, nor even preferable, to have a policy that's 100% "accurate". To make it more accurate you have to make the formulas complicated and put in all kinds of exceptions that make it confusing. And that's exactly the kind of thing that will make the plan fail. For the plan to work it has to be easy to understand. Joe or Jane Member can easily grasp that "For each extra member we bring in above 15, everyone's rate goes down by $16/mo." It makes sense, they can not only understand it but they can remember it, and it may very well motivate them.

But they'll tune out if what they're expected to understand sounds like this:: "So we have 14.7 people with 75% occupancy and for each extra person we get above 14.7 (however that happens) then we take the net revenue calculated by taking the room rate minus a certain amount for food and utilities and divide it by the total number of members, which is the rate reduction, which decreases as we fill up the house because we get more members...." Understanding all that B.S. is hard enough; remembering it is even worse.

The old occupancy bonus we had was actually harder to understand than this. Back when I was trying to reform that bonus I polled several members and board members, and not a single one could describe how it actually worked.

The IRS code is the exact same principle. It's filled with all kinds of crazy exceptions and special calculations to try to make everything more accurate. And that's why it's so ridiculously complicated.

With a simplified system the members might get shortchanged by 15% or they might get 15% that they don't "deserve". That's okay. It's perfectly acceptable to trade a little accuracy for something that everyone can easily understand, and actually participate in.

The plan isn't 100% perfect. I identified minor flaws A, B, and C.

Congratulations. The fact is that no plan is perfect. That doesn't mean you throw away the plan. If you can't make any changes to make the plan perfect, then you simply have to decide whether the flawed plan is better than the current system. In this case, is it worth giving members the opportunity to save $80/mo. on their rooms, or do we shrug our shoulders and keep rates high because the plan isn't perfect? The choice is yours.

Making this a reality

Board members and staff can probably think of ways to make this plan better. As I mentioned I caution against making the plan any more complicated or harder to understand, but besides that, there is almost certainly room for improvement.

For this plan to become a reality a board member will have to propose it. I can't do so because I'm not on the board. I therefore challenge board members to take this idea and run with it. And house members, if you like the idea but your board rep isn't doing anything about it, ask them to do so. This plan won't happen on its own. Members have to make their voices heard.

Good luck!

 


Appendices

Historical Summer Occupancy Rates
(% of available beds, for entire summer)

2003
2002

Avalon

61
80

French House

73
85

Helios

(spruce up)
74

House of Commons

70
75

New Guild

44
(spruce up)

Royal

78
79

Seneca Falls

89
92

All

56.1
63.9
Note: The snapshot occupancy figures on 8/7/03 and 8/8/02 weren't much different than this -- 2003: 63, 73, -, 72, 43, 73, 89. 2002: 76, 81, 73, 67, - 78, 95

Factors driving lower summer occupancy

Howard notes:

Somes Reasons members leave ICC and Austin in the summer:
  • Cost too high
  • No jobs in Austin, bad economy
  • Can live for free with Parental Units
  • Parents say I have to come home
  • Travel plans
  • Graduation

Of all of the reasons only cost is within our control. No reason not to see if manipulation of that will improve occupancy significantly.

Michael Bluejay's info & resources about

Michael Bluejay's Home Page | Email me

Home Austin Co-ops ICC History Articles & Resources